The Government is
considering establishing a register of the beneficial owners of overseas
companies, the so-called Persons with Significant Control (PSCs). The aim is
the better understanding and regulation of corporate control. I have submitted
some comments to the Call for Evidence drawing on my own research into
corporate ownership and control. My comments concentrate on issues relevant to
the collection and recording of shareholder information. This post comprises
the various suggestions made in my submission.
Originally Posted May 8 2017.
The cut-off
for defining a PSC.
1. There are
great advantages in using the existing definition of PSC, at least in the first
instance. This will allow evolving measures and data collection methods to be
applied in the new context. Any change to definition should be undertaken for
both matters after experience of the system and awareness of any problems have
been gained.
2. The one area
where I think that change is required is in the percentage cut-off used for
identifying a PSC, which is set at 25% (paragraph 32). The proposed cut-off
level is too high and will not capture many situations where there is a
significant controlling interest. The rationale behind this recommendation is set
out at length in my book Capitalist Property and Financial Power (Harvester
Press, 1986), which reviewed international data on the distribution of share
ownership and the implications for control. The clear conclusion was that no
arbitrary figure for control can be set as the percentage shareholding required
depends upon the overall distribution of voting share capital in the company.
In broad terms, the greater the dispersal of the share capital, the lower the
percentage required for control. Where there are large blocks of shares, 25%,
30%, or more may be required. However, when the bulk of the shares are held in
small blocks of less than 1%, significant control is possible with a holding of
10%.
3. Evidence
reported in the book already mentioned and in Corporate Business and
Capitalist Classes (Oxford University Press, 1997) shows that the most
significant companies in Britain (and elsewhere) are those in which shares are
dispersed among numerous financial institutions and custodian holdings. In
these companies, an interest can acquire control by building up a 10% holding
as there are no rival blocks of shares or coalitions of shareholders. While
control may be possible with even less than this, I suggest that a 10% cut-off
is likely to capture most cases of significant control. A cut-off of 25% will
miss a significant number of cases of genuine control and predominating
influence.
Control over
blocks of votes by fund managers.
4. Attention
has to be given to the discovery of voting blocks. The Consultation document
discusses the case of beneficial trusts and of custodian holdings, but does not
consider the implications of the ways in which voting control over shares is
actually managed today.
5. Among the most
significant shareholders today are pension funds, unit trusts, and similar
bodies, where share are held for the benefit of large numbers of individuals.
Such holdings are not, in themselves, bases of control (and are often,
individually, below the cut-off threshold). However, the beneficiaries are
rarely those who exercise the voting rights attached to the shares. The
research that I have undertaken, reported in the books above, shows that the
voting rights are generally held by the fund managers who operate the nominee
accounts or work through the custodians.
6. Typically,
the shares held by, for example, a pension fund will be divided among two or
three fund managers. These fund managers will also act on behalf of other
pension funds and unit trusts. Even allowing for the ‘Chinese walls’ that exist
between the businesses of various clients and the fund manager’s own business
holdings, it is the case that large blocks of votes are effectively exercised
by large fund managers.
7. There is,
therefore, no direct mapping between the distribution of trust and custodian
holdings in a register, on the one hand, and the distribution of voting powers
on the other. The distribution of voting power can be discovered only by direct
investigation into the detailed management of each nominee and custodian holding
on the register and obtaining responses in detail from all fund managers
involved.
8. This
mobilisation of voting blocks is typically the case in the largest companies
and allows fund managers who do not appear in the share register to accumulate
blocks of , typically, 3%-6% of votes. It is possible, however, for those
seeking control to acquire larger blocks that put them above the cut-off
threshold for control. The proposals as currently set out would not capture
these cases.
Problems of
enforcement over disclosure.
9.
Particular problems arise in tracking back the ultimate beneficiary or
controller of overseas companies. The use of chains of intermediaries and of
the dispersal of voting blocks makes identification problematic. It also means
that legal compulsion to disclose information cannot easily operate. British
companies can be compelled by law, but those who operate overseas, with bases
often in special fiscal jurisdictions, cannot be so compelled – and if their
control is not identified there cannot even be any attempt at enforcement.
These issues are well-explored in research by academics such as Prem Sikka of
Essex University (No Accounting for Tax Havens, with Austin Mitchell and
others, 2002; and other publications).
10. A specific
issue arises for those countries where bearer shares are common. In these
cases, voting and beneficial rights are held by the actual holder and no name
is registered with the company. Identifying the PSC in foreign companies with
bearer share capital is likely to be impossible. Such shares are, of course,
especially likely to be used where there is a covert attempt to build up
control.
Originally Posted May 8 2017.
Comments
Post a Comment